NGO Another Way (Stichting Bakens
Verzet), 1018 AM
SELF-FINANCING,
ECOLOGICAL, SUSTAINABLE, LOCAL INTEGRATED DEVELOPMENT PROJECTS FOR THE WORLD’S
POOR
FREE
E-COURSE FOR DIPLOMA IN INTEGRATED DEVELOPMENT |
|||||
Edition 01 :15 June, 2013.
(VERSION EN FRANÇAIS PAS DISPONIBLE)
Summaries of
monetary reform papers by L.F. Manning published at http://www.integrateddevelopment.org.
Chicago Plan Revisited Version II: An insufficient
response to financial system failure. (Posted 11 May, 2013.)
Comments on the (Jaromir
Benes and Michael Kumhof) Chicago Plan Revisited Paper.
DNA of the debt-based economy.
General summary of all papers published.(Revised edition).
How to create stable financial systems in four
complementary steps. (Revised edition).
How to introduce an e-money financed virtual minimum wage
system in New Zealand. (Revised edition) .
How
to introduce a guaranteed minimum income in New Zealand. (Revised edition).
Interest-bearing debt system and its economic impacts.
(Revised edition).
Manifesto of 95 principles of the debt-based economy.
Manning plan for permanent debt reduction in the national economy.
Missing links between growth, saving, deposits and
GDP.
Savings Myth. (Revised edition).
There’s no such thing as affordable housing.
Unified text of the manifesto of the debt-based
economy.
Using a foreign transactions surcharge (FTS) to manage the
exchange rate.
(The
following items have not been revised. They show the historic development of
the work. )
Financial system mechanics explained for the first time. “The Ripple Starts
Here.”
Short summary of the paper The Ripple Starts Here.
Financial system mechanics: Power-point presentation.
This
work is licensed under a Creative
Commons Attribution-Non-commercial-Share Alike 3.0 Licence
THERE’S
NO SUCH THING AS AFFORDABLE HOUSING.
By
Sustento Institute,
08 June, 2013.
Version 4 : Distribution
2.
Email: manning@kapiti.co.nz ; bakensverzet@x4all.nl
Edition 01 :15 June, 2013.
The concept of “affordable
housing” is political propaganda, a hand washing exercise so governments can
“feel good” while household home ownership rates in
Property, especially
residential property, is one of the few genuine “markets” left in
Everyone in the property
business knows that property values are the sum of the land value and the value
of improvements.
The main value of the
improvements is the house or other building on the land. That building has a
cost made up of materials, labour, council and government compliance costs and
the like. The cost of housing in
A cheaper building has to be
smaller and simpler and use relatively lower grade fittings, because everything
else is controlled by the applicable standards and regulations. So, a
government that talks about a cheap or
affordable house it is really talking about a lesser house in respect of
size, comfort and quality.
Since house “costs” do not govern
the variation in property values, the land value must be doing so. Wide
variations in land values mean they are subjectively assessed according to
location and demand. Those factors determine the relative value of land from
one place to the other, but not the value
of the land in aggregate.
The aggregate “value” of the
land portion of the property is determined by the pool of investment money
available to purchase and exchange it, not by the land itself or government
policy.
Residential property forms a
large part of the value of unproductive capital investment in all developed
countries. When the banking system deposits increase sharply, so will land
prices in aggregate, and therefore
property prices in aggregate, but not the
prices of the improvements on them. This is true for all non-productive investments in
equities and commercial paper as well. The relative weighting of non-commercial
property, equities, government and commercial paper, and bank deposits depends
on regulatory policy settings such as tax rates, lending criteria, subsidies
and the perceived impact of offshore events.
In
The year to year correlation
of the two graphs in Figure 1 is low because housing is only one of four areas
of non-productive investment, the others being equities, government and
commercial paper, and bank deposits.
Investors always have a choice
where to invest. For example, during the dotcom boom, equities were preferred
relative to residential housing. House prices at that time fell briefly while
bank borrowing surged.
The M3 data also reflects changes
induced by offshore “crises”. From 2002 to 2007, after the dotcom crash,
housing was relatively preferred to other forms of investment as Figure 1 shows
clearly. The plunge in property prices in 2008 and 2009 largely reflects
investor withdrawal from the housing market in sympathy with the
In the March years 2011 and 2012 the rate of the increase in house
prices was less than that for M3 because equities prices rose very
quickly. Yet there was no move by the
Note that 0.945*M3 is used in the graph in Figure 1
because the productive transaction account deposits used to physically generate
the GDP are not part of the non-productive investment sector. The author estimates the productive
transaction account deposits are presently about 5.5% of GDP in
Figure 1: New Zealand 1993-2013
: % Change in House Price v. 0.945*M3.
The trend lines in Figure 1 rest
almost on top of one another. That shows that over the past 20 years house
prices have followed the money supply (0.945*M3) available to the investment
sector, not the physical cost of building houses or of developing land.
A government or a territorial
authority that “forces” housing development in chosen areas is literally
squeezing on a housing balloon. In
The only way to reduce the
rise in real property “values” in aggregate, and residential housing prices in
particular, is to slow the increase in the money supply as a whole. Unfortunately
for the government the money supply growth
in the existing debt-based financial system is systemic. It cannot arbitrarily be reduced below the trend line shown in Figure 1 without wrecking
the economy.
The mechanics of the debt
system are fully described by
the author in Financial system mechanics
explained for the first time. “The Ripple Starts Here”, a paper presented at the annual conference of the
New Zealand Association of Economists’ 50th in July, 2009. The paper
develops a simple debt model of the economy. Later updated papers are also
available at www.integrateddevelopment.org. The paper shows that systemic inflation is
the net deposit interest paid on deposits, while the systemic inflation rate is the net interest expressed as %
GDP.
The debt system mechanics
require that the total money supply increases by an amount sufficient to cover
systemic inflation (presently about 1.75%)
plus “growth” (say 1.5% after deducting a productivity increase of about
1%) plus domestic deposits that
result from the current account deficit. A positive balance of trade is counted
as GDP “growth” but it does not appear in domestic deposits because it is “used up” to reduce the size of the current account deficit. The GDP “growth”
figures in the official data for
In
As discussed below, the excessive investment sector growth in debtor
countries like
Figure 2: New Zealand 0.945*M3
v GDP 1986-2012.
Figure 3: New Zealand
1986-2012:Growth of GDP and M3*0.945.
The trendlines in Figure 3 are
exponential because the payment of deposit interest in the interest-bearing
debt system creates systemic inflation as mentioned on page 4. The net
additional flow of deposits from the current account deficit creates a
different exponential rate of growth of the investment sector relative to
GDP. That differential rate of growth has been about 0.7%/year over the period
1986-2012. The exponentials
shown in Figure 3 (5.2%, 7.8%) cannot be compared directly because the curves
in Figure 3 have different starting points. If the data series are set at the
same starting point (52.7) the 0.945*M3 exponential would be 5.9 instead of
7.8. This shows that 0.945*M3 increased 0.7%/year faster than GDP from
1986-2012.
Due mainly to the current
account deficits, the investment sector has grown at 5.9%/year while nominal
GDP has grown at 5.2%/year over the same period. That is why prices in the
non-productive investment sector are “overvalued”.
While nominal GDP has grown by
$159.2 billion, 0.945*M3 has grown by $196.3 billion, a difference of $37.1 billion. That extra $37.1 billion represents
surplus deposits over and above those needed to fund the principal outstanding
on capital investments in the capitalist system. The total surplus is more than $37.1 billion because the accumulated
surplus from before 1985 needs to be added. The total is thought to be a little
over $40 billion.
The author’s paper the “DNA of the debt-based economy”
demonstrates that GDP equals the outstanding principal on capital
investments. Were the growth of 0.945* M3
to exactly follow the growth of nominal GDP, the increase in the prices of
existing capital assets in aggregate
would mirror GDP growth. As shown in equation (1) below, it is mathematically
impossible for the total deposits to be lower than the existing
interest-bearing debt in the capitalist system after subtracting the banks’
residual (net worth) that they have “captured” from the deposit base (mostly
their net retained profits) and the country’s net foreign currency debt.
Debt figures used in this article exclude secondary
savings and loan debt such as the on-lending of deposits through finance
companies and other non-bank financial institutions. Secondary debt is thought
to amount to about 10% of Domestic Credit in
Debt is linked to deposits and the current account/NIIP by the formula:
(DC + NFCA) = M3 + Residual (1)
Assets = Deposit Liabilities + Net worth
Use of the
Net International Investment Position, (NIIP) in equation (1) might be a little
more accurate but the author uses the
current account for simplicity.
The formula represents the basic accounting equation viewed from the
banks’ point of view, where DC is Domestic Credit, M3 is the total bank
deposits, NCFA is the Net Foreign Currency Assets of the banking system and
Residual is the net worth of the banking system. The Residual is positive when the equation is in that
form, and NFCA is negative for debtor countries.
The numbers for
DC was $333.2 billion.
NFCA was $-52,6 billion.
M3 was $ 253,6 billion.
Residual was + $ 27.0 billion.
Applying Formula (1) to
$333.2 b - $52.6b = $253.6b + $27.0b
At that time,
-
- $151.2b (the accumulated current account deficit
$203.8 b.- the net foreign currency assets $52.6 b.) of the deposits created to
fund the accumulated current account deficit had therefore been returned to New
Zealand in the form of foreign ownership,
The annual GDP for 2012
($209.3b) x 1.055%, or $220.8b, of the $253.6b M3 deposit base was needed for
capital and to fund the productive transaction accounts. The productive
transaction accounts in
The multiplier 1.055 is used
because the dynamic transaction account balance (0.055* GDP) must be added to
GDP (the net outstanding principal on capital investments) to get the minimum
debt needed to fund a capitalist economy before taking into account the NFCA
and bank Residual.
The domestic money supply M3 ($253.6b) –
the annual GDP for 2012 $209.3b x 1.055%] ($220.8b) gives an amount of
$32.8b.
Between
1985 and 2012
Recent IMF comments that
housing in
In
New Zealand therefore remains
at risk of further asset inflation should the present arbitraging of interest
rates by the New Zealand banks be reversed. As shown on page 7, the banks have
borrowed a net amount of $52.6b, the
NFCA, offshore. They have done so because it is cheaper for them to do that than
pay deposit interest in
International financial institutions
are concerned with financial stability. They are not concerned about the
economic asymmetry that foreign ownership of a domestic economy creates. Nor
are they concerned about domestic imbalances in wealth and income distribution.
If the banks were to stop borrowing money abroad to finance their operations,
most of the NFCA of $52.6 billion would be invested in existing assets in
There are two main options to
“pop” the housing “investment bubble”. Neither of them has anything to do with
building houses!
In
The
The second option makes more
sense because it removes a primary source
of the structural asset “bubble”, namely the persistent growth of foreign
ownership through the current account. Reversing that growth means managing the
exchange rate, but the government and it advisors like the Treasury and the
Reserve Bank of
The government could easily
set up a variable and tax neutral Foreign Transactions Surcharge (FTS) as set
out in the paper Using a foreign transactions
surcharge (FTS) to manage the exchange rate. The FTS is an
automatically collected levy on all outward domestic currency transactions
passing through the foreign exchange interface. Its effect would be to increase the aggregate cost of
repatriating domestic currency offshore and lower the aggregate cost of using
domestic currency locally. The revenue obtained from the levy would be used
only to reduce domestic taxation and to begin repayments of foreign debt, in
effect repurchasing those assets already ceded to foreigners. While an FTS will
correct the exchange rate and current account it will have little immediate
effect on investment prices or the property market. It would instead lead to a
gradual easing of the rate of investment price increases over time.
There is no such thing as
affordable housing. There is just a
housing market. Aggregate prices in that market are structural. Any government attempt to manipulate the market without
addressing the structural causes of property inflation will fail. The sooner
the government introduces a program to resolve the main issue of foreign
ownership generated through the current account deficit, the sooner house
prices will become more stable.
Summaries of monetary reform
papers by L.F. Manning published at http://www.integrateddevelopment.org.
Chicago Plan Revisited Version II: An insufficient
response to financial system failure. (Posted 11 May, 2013.)
Comments on the IMF (Benes and Kumhof) paper “The
Chicago Plan Revisited”.
DNA of the debt-based economy.
General summary of all papers
published.(Revised
edition).
How to create stable financial systems in four
complementary steps. (Revised edition).
How to introduce an e-money financed virtual minimum wage
system in New Zealand. (Revised edition) .
How
to introduce a guaranteed minimum income in New Zealand. (Revised edition).
Interest-bearing debt system and its economic impacts.
(Revised edition).
Manifesto of 95 principles of the debt-based economy.
The Manning plan for permanent debt reduction in the national economy.
Missing links between growth, saving, deposits and
GDP.
Savings Myth. (Revised edition).
Unified text of the manifesto of the debt-based
economy.
Using a foreign transactions surcharge (FTS) to manage the
exchange rate.
(The
following items have not been revised. They show the historic development of
the work. )
Financial system mechanics explained for the first time. “The Ripple
Starts Here.”
Short summary of the paper The Ripple Starts Here.
Financial system mechanics: Power-point presentation.
"Money
is not the key that opens the gates of the market but the bolt that bars
them."
Gesell,
Silvio, The Natural Economic Order, revised English edition, Peter Owen,
This work is
licensed under a Creative
Commons Attribution-Non-commercial-Share Alike 3.0 Licence.