ONG Stichting Bakens Verzet (Une Autre Voie), 1018 AM Amsterdam, Pays Bas.
Édition
02: 03 Septembre, 2009
01. Cours e-learning :
Diplôme de Développement Intégré (Dip. Dév. Int)
SECTION A : LES PROBLÈMES DU
DÉVELOPPEMENT.
Valeur attribuée : 04 points sur
18
Travail prévu : 112 heures sur
504
Les points ne sont attribués qu’après
le complètement réussi de l’examen consolidé pour
Premier bloc : La pauvreté et la qualité de vie.
Valeur attribuée : 02 points sur 18
Travail prévu : 57 heures sur 504
Les points ne sont attribués qu’après le
complètement réussi de l’examen consolidé pour
Premier Bloc
: Section 2. Les services à la base d’une bonne qualité de vie. [26.50 heures]
[06.50 Heures] Analyse du
matériel du Modèle.
[14.00 Heures]
Approfondissement.
[06.00 Heures] Rédaction de
votre rapport.
Premier Bloc
: Section 2. Les services à la base d’une bonne qualité de vie. [26.50 heures]
[06.50 Heures] Analyse
matériel du Modèle.
01. Les bases d’une bonne qualité de vie.
05. Schéma typique d’une zone de forage/puits.
08. La santé et l’assainissement.
09. Système complet de recyclage des ordures.
10. Toilette à compostage à sec.
13. Système de sécurité sociale.
Premier Bloc
: Section 2. Les services à la base d’une bonne qualité de vie. [26.50 heures]
[06.50 Heures] Analyse
matériel du Modèle.
12. Travail pour tous. (Dédier au moins 30 minutes à cette
section).
On
fait une analyse du sixième facteur retenu nécessaire à une bonne qualité de
vie : le travail pour tous.
Consultez
la diapositive :
Qu’est-ce que c’est que ça, le «travail » ?
Repassez les notes que vous avez fait au début du cours, à la Section 1 du Bloc 1 : 02
Quelques facteurs liés à la pauvreté : approfondissement . De nombreuses
activités formelles retenues “productives” des économes et qui contribuent à la
formation du Produit Brut National n’augmentent pas la qualité de vie des
populations. De nombreuses activités informelles retenues “improductives” des
économes contribuent bien à la qualité de vie des populations mais sont exclues
de la formation du Produit Brut National.
Lisez l’article suivant de
“2.1.03 Monetisation and the
economy
Standards for economic comparisons are most often
developed by western economists who fail to take the non-monetised part of
economies into account. Yet only a relatively small part of the world's global
economy is "monetised". The percentage represented by the monetised
part of the economy tends to be higher in “industrialised” countries than it is
in less developed economies. However, even in the most “developed”
industrialised countries, only part of the real productive economy is
“monetised”.
“The output of domestic and personal services
produced for own consumption within households is not included [in the Output
product for own final use (p.12)]” (The 1993 SNA System of
National Accounts, United Nations Statistics Division, Section VI The Production Account, par. 6.46). [Pour la
version en français voir Le Système de comptabilité nationale 1993 (SCN)]
If one were to proceed to subtract the
percentage of negative economic parasitic activities in industrialised nations
from positive productive ones, the difference between the net pro-capita
productivity of industrial countries and that of developing economies might
turn out not to be so big as one might imagine. For instance, the costs in
time, use of infrastructure, fuel consumption, and equipment write-off of a
western commuter who loses four hours a day in queues going to and returning
home from work are monetised though they tend to have a negative weighting on
our quality of life. They become part of our so-called gross national product.
Benefits enjoyed by an African herdsman who spends the same four hours a day in
the shade of a tree discussing philosophy with his friends are not monetised.
Yet which of them has the better quality of life at least during those four
hours? How do the individuals involved perceive their quality of life during
those four hours? How far is their quality of life directly influenced by money
in such cases?
One acceptable way of assessing productivity is
by connecting it with the length of a human life. While life expectancy varies
from one country to another, most of us divide a day into 24 hours. Most of us
spend about eight hours sleeping, which means our potential active productivity
has to be fitted into the remaining 16 hours per day. We assume, for the
purposes of making an example, an average life span of 75 years. Appropriate
allowance has to be made for children. This allowance varies according to the
customs and conditions of life in any given community. Let us assume the
allowance is 15 years. No account is taken in this example of old age. Our
potentially productive life-span is then 75 years (life span) minus 15 years
(unproductive childhood) or 60 years. Our total potential for productivity is
in that case 60 years x 365 days x 16 hours, or about 350.000 hours. The time each individual has available for
active productivity is therefore finite.
On an average, it is potentially comparable but not the same for every
individual or for every community. How an individual chooses or is able to use
the time potentially available to him for active productivity (in the example
350.000 hours) is in theory very subjective. In practice, however, it is
usually subjected to restrictions. In
some cases, such as slavery, the individual may have no choice at all.
Any
activity which tends to improve the quality of life of the individual and of
the family and community he or she lives in is productive. Any activity which
does not tend to improve one’s quality of life or that of the family and
community he or she lives in is unproductive. Viewed this way, four hours spent
by a woman cleaning the family home and preparing food for dinner is
productive. The fours hours spent by a commuter in his car going to and
returning from work are essentially unproductive, as are the use of
infrastructure, fuel consumption, and equipment write-off involved. The work of
the woman improves the quality of life of her family; the time spent by the
commuter in his car in general does not.
Since women constitute about 50% of the world’s
population, the productivity of women at home, working in the fields, bringing
up children, helping elderly family members already represents at least 50% of
the real productive economy. This productivity does not usually change much
even where women also have a job outside of their home environments. Since many
women work domestically this way at least 12 hours a day without payment
compared with a theoretic average of 8 hours a day their husbands actually
spend at their paid work, percentages of 60% non-monetised activity and 40%
monetised activity already arise in western economies even before other factors
are taken into account. If unemployed, the sick, the handicapped, and people on
a benefit together with other common activities such as voluntary work,
gardening and the like are also considered, the monetised productivity quota in
a developed economy is in reality considerably
lower than 40%. It may not exceed 20%.
In some developing countries the monetised part
of the economy may be as small as 10% of a country’s notional national product.
The application of universal income policies
might lead to some changes in this field. This is because the universal income
system recognises, amongst other things, the productivity of women in the home,
and the productivity of students during their study. However, universal income
is apparently not considered by the elites currently holding economic power to
be in their favour. So no country has yet adopted it. The important and useful
traditional work of many women in looking after children and doing household
chores is therefore not monetised, even in Western countries. Nor are the
numerous other productive activities conducted by family members in general
outside their period of paid employment and professional activities.”
Pour des informations plus détaillées sur ce sujet lisez : Analyzing the Policy Implications of Time Use Data, United
Nations Economics and Social Commission for Asia and the Pacific (ESCAP),
Document de discussion rédigé pour l’atelier ESCAP “Workshop for High
Level Policy Makers on Counting Policy Implications of Time Use Survey Data”,
11-15 Septembre 2000, Bangkok, Thailand. Cet article n’est lui aussi disponible
qu’en anglais.
À la page 2 du
rapport écrit-on :
“Un mouvement progressif des activités du secteur des
ménages non monétisés à l’économie monétisée est à la base du procès de
développement. Toutefois les économes,
sous l’influence dominante de l’école néo-classique, se sont limités à la
considération des phénomènes qui ont lieu à l’intérieur de l’économie
monétisée.”
Le Modèle de Développement
Intégré :
a) Considère comme
productive toute activité qui augmente la qualité de vie de la population et
improductive toute activité qui ne le
fait pas..
b) Accepte que beaucoup (la
plupart) des activités productives ne sont pas monétisées, tandis que beaucoup
des activités improductives le sont.
c) Prévoit un système de monnaie
locale qui permet la monétisation de facto de toutes les activités productives
dans chaque zone de projet.
1. Recherches.
Sur la base de tels principes,
faites une analyse des heures d’activité «productive » d’une femme
moyenne et d’un homme moyen dans votre zone.
Calculez le total des heures
d’activité productive dans votre zone.
Multipliez les heures d’activité
productive par le salaire horaire moyen applicable au secteur formel dans votre
zone.
Calculez le rapport entre la
valeur totale (exprimée en monnaie formelle) des activités productives que vous
avez obtenu et celle présentée pour votre zone
dans les statistiques nationales
calculés avec le méthode du Système de
comptabilité nationale 1993 (SCN) .
◄ Premier bloc : Section 2.
◄ Premier bloc : La
pauvreté et la qualité de vie.
◄ Table matières pour le Diplôme du Développement
Intégré (D.Dév.Int).
Cette
œuvre est mise dans le domaine public aux termes d’une licence
Creative Commons
Attribution-Non-commercial-Share Alike 3.0.